Understanding Correlation

crispydocUncategorized 2 Comments

The gifts of the WCI Con 20 swag bag just keep on giving! Sheltering in place has provided ample reading time to sneak in some continuing financial education, currently on how achieve desired returns with reduced volatility. I'm currently reading Swedroe and Grogan's 2018 edition of Reducing the Risk of Black Swans, which has the most lucid explanation of correlation I've ever read.

In case the timely title is not sexy enough to catch your attention, I'll paraphrase their explanation as a teaser to encourage more of you pick up this fascinating, evidence-based read.

Correlation among asset classes is important to understand in order to create a portfolio with reduced volatility. Let's take two theoretical assets, A and B. Each has a tendency to produce returns that will be either above or below its unique average.

If A and B are positively correlated, then when A produces above average returns, B is also likely to produce above average returns. Correlation cuts both ways, however, meaning that when A produces below average returns, B is also likely to produce below average returns. The stronger this likelihood, the closer the correlation between A and B will be to 1.

If A and B are negatively correlated, then when A produces above average returns, B is likely to produce below average returns (and vice versa). The stronger this likelihood, the closer the correlation between A and B approaches -1. Note that we are describing probabilities, not immutable laws. A negative correlation is not a guarantee that when A zigs, B will zag; rather it suggests that when A zigs, B is more likely to zag.

Here's where most investors get a bit confused. The ideal portfolio is not composed of negatively correlated assets, but rather, one composed of uncorrelated assets. What's the difference? If A and B are uncorrelated, then when A produces above average returns, B's returns are equally likely to be above or below average, independent of A's returns. Their correlation is zero.

Let's use a sample of a 4 year sequence of returns to illustrate: A has returns of 8%,12%,8%,12%, for a positive average annual return of 10%. During those same 4 years, B has returns of 12%,8%,12%,8% for a positive average annual return of 10%. Looks like A and B are negatively correlated. You'll also note that both produced positive returns.

In our second 4 year sample, A has returns of 3%,-3%,3%,-3%, for an average annual return of zero percent. During those same 4 years, B has returns of -3%,3%,-3%,3%, also for an average annual return of zero percent. A and B both produce annual returns of zero percent, and they remain negatively correlated.

Now for the financial hat trick. Let's sum these two 4 year series into a single 8 year sample for each asset.

Returns for A: 8,12,8,12,3,-3,3,-3.

Returns for B:12,8,12,8,-3,3,-3,3.

Average 8 year returns for A are 4%. Average 8 year returns for B are also 4%. Uh oh, weren't these assets negatively correlated? Nope! We know that over 8 years they each have an average return of 4%. In the first series, during the 4 years when A provided above average returns, B also achieved above average returns. In the second series, during the 4 years when A provided below average returns, B also achieved below average returns. This suggests a positive correlation over a longer series. Mind blown.

Lesson: Correlations are only meaningful if examining a series of data over a long period of time.

The authors go on to impart a second lesson, one that is not necessarily demonstrated by the example above but is important to keep in mind: in a market crash, the only thing that goes up is correlation. Put another way, during a time of crisis, correlations go to 1. I learned that one firsthand in 2008, when my REITs behaved like equities.

I encourage those of you who enjoy this type of discussion to check out Reducing the Risk of Black Swans, and let me know what you think!

Comments 2

  1. The problem we have is that there’s no markets anymore.
    The central banks have created a Potemkin market. A casino economy and fake money.
    And de facto correlated all assets.
    Worldwide.
    That’s the problem.
    There’s no real escaping the fake markets. Unless you separate them into real and financial assets. And not forgetting that most real physical assets have a corresponding hologram that trades but is fake as well.
    In the end, that’s all we have left: reality.
    Anything is an illusion. Including net worth.

    1. Post
      Author

      Cresus,

      Always happy to receive financial insights from an ancient King of Lydia renowned for his wealth – thanks for stopping by.

      As an investor, learning more about how markets frequently function as if divorced from reality certainly has a scales falling from the eyes quality of feeling lied to and disillusioned that every player has equal opportunity to profit over time. Recent reading on high frequency traders has especially brought that point home.

      As for the market reflecting the economy – that’s not the case now, and probably never has been. It’s a folie a dieux scaled to include every investor, so when the market does not reflect the economy – something brilliant minds coming from places as different as Paul Krugman in the NY Times and Gasem on his blog can agree on – what we are witnessing is the animal spirits that Keynes wrote about so long ago. The economy is what we produce and sell. The market is how we feel, and feelings are fickle (as anyone in love with someone who does not reciprocate knows only too well) not to mention volatile.

      One of the interesting and more controversial perspectives I’ve gathered from economists is that there seems to be a potentially protective effect to printing vast quantities of fake money during a crisis – not because doing so is based on underlying assets, but because the illusory stability it provides seems to influence those animal spirits that are so decisive in determining the scope and severity of a recession or depression. For a great example, check out how a group of University of Chicago trained economists created the illusion of price stability during an economic free fall in Chile under Pinochet that developed from virtual into actual economic stability.

      Do I support the practice? Like gravity, whether I support it or not, it’s going to affect me. Do I object to it as strenuously as many people I respect – probably less so since it has seemed to provide a softer landing for more people. In fact, one of the interesting critiques of Greece in 2008 was that it’s membership in the EU hamstrung its ability to print more of its own currency (Germany was not going to sign off on that move), placing it in a weaker position where creditor nations could only insist on increasing levels of austerity measures – a movie that has ended badly every time its played.

      As to the illusion of net worth – perhaps for someone pursuing FI it provides a sought after false sense of reassurance. Perhaps it only functions in the greater fool theory if one can, indeed, guarantee a steady supply of greater fools on which to unload your securities.

      So perhaps printing money is in effect creating the supply of greater fools that guarantees a predictably dysfunctional market? Not excited where my logic takes me on that one…

      Appreciate the brain candy,

      CD

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.